Questions remain about just how many more US exports China’s promised to buy to avert a trade war: US officials have floated the figure of $200 billion annually, which would cut the bilateral trade deficit in half. Even if that were true, however -- and Chinese officials have denied it -- that massive buying spree wouldn’t bring down the overall US trade deficit one whit.
China should be able to rebalance its trade relationship with the US relatively quickly by reorienting its purchases of industrial and agricultural commodities, along with some industrial products such as aircraft. As a large importer of commodities, it’s easy enough for China simply to shift its buying from one country to another. Unfortunately, any increase in US exports to China will inevitably be matched by a reduction in US exports to other countries.
To understand why, we must understand the role of the US in stabilizing global trade and capital imbalances. Under the current global system, the distribution of income in a number of countries -- not just China, but also Germany, Japan, South Korea and several others -- is distorted in favor of government and businesses rather than households. This is because these economies effectively subsidize manufacturing exports with various hidden transfers from households, including low wages and low deposit rates. The household share of income is consequently too low for domestic demand to absorb everything produced domestically.
Such distortions also lead to structurally high savings rates in these countries. Income can be consumed or it can be saved. Households consume most of their income while governments and businesses typically save all or nearly all of theirs. By giving the latter a disproportionately high share of income, and households a disproportionately low share, these countries automatically force up their savings rates.
The global economy, in other words, suffers from excess savings generated by a small group of high-surplus countries. The US plays a stabilizing role by absorbing nearly half of this excess of global savings. That’s not because the US has any need for such huge amounts of foreign savings, but because it has completely open, deep and flexible capital markets.
If foreign countries export excess savings to the US, driving up its capital account surplus, then by definition the US must also run a current account deficit. This means that US investment must exceed US savings by exactly the amount of foreign savings exported into the US.
If the US were a developing country that needed money to invest, as was true for most of the 19th century, this imported capital would be a huge boon, allowing it to invest more than it otherwise could.
But, that’s no longer the case. Not only do American businesses have all the capital they need to invest, and at historically low interest rates, they’re sitting on piles of cash whose only use is to fund non-productive stock buybacks. The US, in other words, suffers from weak demand and excessive savings.
If all these foreign capital inflows don’t drive up US investment, then they must drive down US savings: This is an unbreakable rule of the balance of payments. They can do so in a number of ways, including by strengthening the currency, reducing lending spreads, increasing unemployment, weakening lending standards or inflating real estate or stock market bubbles that boost consumption through a wealth effect. All of these processes force down US savings to below its investment rate.
So, even if China did somehow reduce its bilateral trade surplus with the US by $200 billion, it would make little difference to overall US trade imbalances. As long as China and other surplus countries continue to save far more than they can invest domestically, and as long as much of the capital they export ends up in America, the US will continue to run large capital account surpluses and the corresponding trade deficits.
If the Trump administration genuinely wants to reduce the overall US trade deficit, it is going to have to address capital imbalances with the whole world, not just China. For their part, Chinese leaders understand that their country suffers from serious domestic imbalances that create trade surpluses harmful to its own economy. While they’ve genuinely been trying to rebalance since at least 2007, this is a difficult process and they’ve had limited success.
Rather than strong-arming China into buying more, the US would be better off promoting such domestic rebalancing efforts, for example by gradually reducing the ability of foreigners to dump their excess savings in the US. This is the only way to force down the overall American deficit and the good news is that it can be done without highly inefficient trade intervention. That would be a deal worth touting.
Michael Pettis
Michael Pettis is a professor of finance at the Guanghua School of Management at Peking University in Beijing. -- Ed.
(Bloomberg)
China should be able to rebalance its trade relationship with the US relatively quickly by reorienting its purchases of industrial and agricultural commodities, along with some industrial products such as aircraft. As a large importer of commodities, it’s easy enough for China simply to shift its buying from one country to another. Unfortunately, any increase in US exports to China will inevitably be matched by a reduction in US exports to other countries.
To understand why, we must understand the role of the US in stabilizing global trade and capital imbalances. Under the current global system, the distribution of income in a number of countries -- not just China, but also Germany, Japan, South Korea and several others -- is distorted in favor of government and businesses rather than households. This is because these economies effectively subsidize manufacturing exports with various hidden transfers from households, including low wages and low deposit rates. The household share of income is consequently too low for domestic demand to absorb everything produced domestically.
Such distortions also lead to structurally high savings rates in these countries. Income can be consumed or it can be saved. Households consume most of their income while governments and businesses typically save all or nearly all of theirs. By giving the latter a disproportionately high share of income, and households a disproportionately low share, these countries automatically force up their savings rates.
The global economy, in other words, suffers from excess savings generated by a small group of high-surplus countries. The US plays a stabilizing role by absorbing nearly half of this excess of global savings. That’s not because the US has any need for such huge amounts of foreign savings, but because it has completely open, deep and flexible capital markets.
If foreign countries export excess savings to the US, driving up its capital account surplus, then by definition the US must also run a current account deficit. This means that US investment must exceed US savings by exactly the amount of foreign savings exported into the US.
If the US were a developing country that needed money to invest, as was true for most of the 19th century, this imported capital would be a huge boon, allowing it to invest more than it otherwise could.
But, that’s no longer the case. Not only do American businesses have all the capital they need to invest, and at historically low interest rates, they’re sitting on piles of cash whose only use is to fund non-productive stock buybacks. The US, in other words, suffers from weak demand and excessive savings.
If all these foreign capital inflows don’t drive up US investment, then they must drive down US savings: This is an unbreakable rule of the balance of payments. They can do so in a number of ways, including by strengthening the currency, reducing lending spreads, increasing unemployment, weakening lending standards or inflating real estate or stock market bubbles that boost consumption through a wealth effect. All of these processes force down US savings to below its investment rate.
So, even if China did somehow reduce its bilateral trade surplus with the US by $200 billion, it would make little difference to overall US trade imbalances. As long as China and other surplus countries continue to save far more than they can invest domestically, and as long as much of the capital they export ends up in America, the US will continue to run large capital account surpluses and the corresponding trade deficits.
If the Trump administration genuinely wants to reduce the overall US trade deficit, it is going to have to address capital imbalances with the whole world, not just China. For their part, Chinese leaders understand that their country suffers from serious domestic imbalances that create trade surpluses harmful to its own economy. While they’ve genuinely been trying to rebalance since at least 2007, this is a difficult process and they’ve had limited success.
Rather than strong-arming China into buying more, the US would be better off promoting such domestic rebalancing efforts, for example by gradually reducing the ability of foreigners to dump their excess savings in the US. This is the only way to force down the overall American deficit and the good news is that it can be done without highly inefficient trade intervention. That would be a deal worth touting.
Michael Pettis
Michael Pettis is a professor of finance at the Guanghua School of Management at Peking University in Beijing. -- Ed.
(Bloomberg)